19 November 2011

Peak Food


British undercover economist Tim Harford’s recent article, “Malthus’s ghost and baby number 7bn,” about whether the world can feed seven billion people, calls to mind the controversy over Peak Oil.  In 1956 geophysicist M. King Hubbert predicted that US oil production would peak in 1970.  Although his prediction was derided by oil professionals, it turned out to be right on the money.

Hubbert had observed that when a particular oil field reached roughly half of what can economically be produced, production levels off and then declines as producing the remaining half becomes more difficult.  Noting that the discovery of new oil fields in the US had itself peaked in 1930, Hubbert extended his theory to apply to all US oil fields taken as a group.

Peak Oil has now moved to the world stage, where discovery of new oil fields peaked in the 1960s.  When will world oil production level off?  Some say it already has.

The increasing cost and scarcity of post-peak oil production will increase oil prices.  But scarcity caused by the increasing demand of seven billion people will increase prices even more.  That is, Peak Oil’s effect on prices will be trumped by Peak Population.

We were, however, talking about feeding seven billion people, as to which Harford concluded “so far, so good.”  Although the cost of energy used in growing, producing and transporting food is a major component of its cost, food is a renewable resource, not finite like oil and other fossil energy.  Right?

Right -- but the soils in which food is grown can be depleted, and the sources of fresh water to grow it may not be renewable. 

The Green Revolution, powered by high-yield varieties of corn, wheat and rice grown with synthetic fertilizer, fed the surge in world population and livestock after World War II.  But in retrospect, it doesn’t seem so green.  According to a Pew Commission report, it had unwanted ecological impacts “such as aquifer depletion, groundwater contamination, and excess nutrient runoff” precisely because of its reliance on what made it a success -- “monoculture crops, irrigation, application of pesticides, and use of nitrogen and phosphorous fertilizers.”

Now Lester Brown of the Earth Policy Institute raises some startling questions about today’s global economy.  One is whether the US can feed China.  Another is whether China could starve the world.

Following the starvation of 30 million Chinese during Mao Zedong’s Great Leap Forward, Mao refocused China’s agricultural resources on the production of grains.  To create new cropland, China cleared the grasslands in its northwest province.  But overplowing and overpumping of freshwater aquifers in the years since has turned much of its farmland into desert.  Dust storms from northern and western China now envelop Beijing every spring.

The storms are reminiscent of the Dust Bowl in the southern US Great Plains where homesteaders had replaced the prairie grass and other vegetation with endless acres of wheat.  A decade of drought in the 1930s forced 2½ million people to abandon their farms.  This dryland is again being farmed with irrigation from the deepwater or “fossil” Ogallala Aquifer, but fossil aquifers do not replenish themselves.  If the Ogallala goes dry, farming will go back to lower-yield dryland farming if there is sufficient rainfall or cease altogether.         

Land degradation that reduces food-growing productivity is a worldwide concern.  Surveys in the 1980s identified roughly three percent of US soil as degraded and two percent as severely degraded.  A separate analysis showed two-thirds of the degradation was caused by “agricultural activities” (i.e., farming) and most of the rest by livestock overgrazing.  For the world as a whole, degradation is caused by these two factors plus deforestation in approximately equal proportions.

If degradation is not too severe, soil can be maintained and even restored by sound farming techniques such as reduced tillage, fallow periods, cover crops, crop rotation, manuring  and balanced fertilizer application.  But if degradation goes too far, farming will cease altogether.  Soil at that point becomes a non-renewable resource.   

That’s the problem China is facing.  To avoid politically unsettling increases in food prices, it will have to import grain .  The US is the world’s largest grain exporter.

Welcome to Peak Food – which, like Peak Oil and almost every other environmental problem you can think of, is trumped by Peak Population.  “For Americans,” Brown says,

“who live in a country that has been the world’s breadbasket for more than half a century, a country that has never known food shortages or runaway food prices, the world is about to change.  Like it or not, we are going to be sharing our grain harvest with the Chinese, no matter how much it raises our food prices.”

Time to husband our agricultural resources and adopt techniques consistent with a seven billion person world.  Grow food for food, not fuel.  And keep our fresh water free of pollutants from Canadian oil sands and US shale gas mining.

07 November 2011

Politics of Despair


The New York Times has commissioned Adam Davidson to write a column for its Sunday magazine “to demystify complicated economic issues – like whether anyone (C.E.O.’s, politicians, people running for the presidency) can actually create jobs.”  Lest you not read the later columns, he tells you how they’ll come out: “The fact is that creating [jobs] in a far-too-sluggish economy is practically impossible in our current capitalist democracy.”

In one of his own columns and also in the New York Review of Books, the Washington Post’s veteran Washington analyst Ezra Klein has come to a similar conclusion about the Obama administration.  Given the opposition of the Republican party and the Democrats’ tenuous control of the Senate, Obama did pretty much all he could have done to stimulate job creation.  His stimulus package helped forestall another 1930s-type depression and lowered the unemployment rate by several percentage points, but now unemployment is stuck at nine percent and nothing further can be done.

The politics of despair has taken over.

Let’s not forget, however, that there is a way to create jobs in a sluggish economy:  government spending.  The New Deal did it in the 1930s.  During its iconic 100-day (reconvened) session in 1933, the 73rd Congress financed two job programs (the Civilian Conservation Corps and the Public Works Administration) as well as relief for the poor and unemployed and the refinancing of residential mortgages to avoid foreclosure.  After Congress had adjourned, FDR created the Civil Works Administration (CWA) under which the government itself hired four million people for what turned out to be a very bitter winter.

CWA led in 1935 to the more permanent WPA (Works Progress Administration) that over the course of the next eight years spent 11 billion dollars employing 8½ million different people on well over a million projects that rebuilt the country’s infrastructure.  None of these programs cured the unemployment problem, but they did create jobs for workers that the private sector wasn’t hiring.  They put money in the empty pockets of previously unemployed people who promptly spent it, thereby stimulating the private sector to create more jobs to sell the products that the people who were temporarily employed by the government bought.

That as I understand it is what Keynesian stimulus is about.  During a recession reinforced by reduced spending on the part of insecure and out-of-work consumers, if the Federal Reserve has lowered short-term interest rates as much as it can, meaning close to or at the “lower bound” of zero percent, without inducing the private sector to produce enough output and create enough jobs to restore full employment, the economy is caught in a “liquidity trap.”  The surest way out is government spending not only to compensate for the inadequacy of private sector spending but also to stimulate the private sector to spend more.  During a liquidity trap, government can borrow at dirt-cheap rates and spend without driving up inflation or “crowding out” private sector spending.  It therefore makes economic sense for government to utilize idle workers to improve the economy’s infrastructure, as WPA did, while seeding the economy’s recovery to full output and employment.

Of course, FDR had advantages that Obama didn’t.  One was that the depression was much worse than our current recession and had lasted much longer when FDR took office.  As a result, he had overwhelming Democratic majorities in both chambers of Congress and a strong public mandate to do something – anything – to make things better.  Having served four years as Governor of New York that included the depression years and several years during World War I virtually running the Navy Department, he had experience and confidence that Obama lacked.  And while FDR was as fiscally conservative by nature as Obama seems to be, his concern for the needs of working people was greater than his conservatism.

FDR capitalized on these advantages and took swift and decisive action.  By the end of the 100 days, although economic conditions had actually gotten worse, “the feeling everywhere was so much better,” one of his close advisors wrote, and “good will [for FDR] spread like a benison over the land.”  Although FDR never got unemployment below ten percent until the huge stimulus of World War II, average Americans came to feel that FDR was trying to do something for them and stopped despairing.  The Democrats’ reward was long-lasting.  Voters kept them in control of the government for 18 of the next 20 years and in control of the House of Representatives for 58 of the next 62 years.

I suspect that the next opportunity for a Newer Deal, if it comes, will not occur before 2016.  By then the 99 percent will have suffered through eight years of despair and stagnant recovery and resistance to change by the one percent.  If they vote, they will control whether the country changes direction or stays the course.